Spring Sale: On select books, now in the Sales section. Orders placed after Wednesday 18 April, will be processed after Passover. We wish our readers a happy holiday!
Spring Sale
>The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money
More details
Publisher:
Collaborators:
  • Yedi'ot Ahronot - Hemed books
  • Bialick institute
Year:
2006
Catalog number :
45-261002
ISBN:
965-493-240-7
Pages:
300
Language:
Weight:
460 gr.
Cover:
paperback

The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money

Translation:
Synopsis

The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money is generally considered to be the masterwork of the English economist John Maynard Keynes. To a great extent it created the terminology of modern macro-economics. It was published in February 1936. The book ushered in a revolution, commonly referred to as the "Keynesian Revolution", in the way economists thought about the economy, and especially how they thought about the feasibility and wisdom of public sector management of the aggregate level of demand in the economy.

In Keynes' book Essays in Persuasion he looked back on his frustrating attempts to influence public opinion during the Great Depression of the early 1930s. The "General Theory" represented Keynes's attempt to shift opinion by altering the framework of thought in macro-economics.

Briefly, the "General Theory" argued that the level of employment in a modern economy was determined by three factors: the marginal propensity to consume (the percentage of any increase in their income that people chose to spend on goods and services), the marginal efficiency of capital(dependent on anticipated rates of return) and the rate of interest. Keynes's key arguments included that in an economy bedevilled by weak demand (e.g. a depression), where in his terminology there was an ignition problem (a difficulty in getting the economy to move forward more vigorously), then the government (more broadly the public sector) could increase aggregate demand by increasing its expenditures, including by borrowing to finance the expenditures, and that the public-sector borrowing would not increase interest rates sufficiently to undermine the effectiveness of such a policy.

Keynes forecast in the "General Theory" that his book was likely to lead to a revolution in the way men of affairs thought about public policy, and Keynesianism (government attempts to affect demand through tax, expenditure and borrowing and monetary policy) was enormously influential in the post-Second World War period. The stagflation of the 1970s made Keynes's interventionist approach less fashionable with politicians and economic theorists. In most economies it came to be believed that Keynesian demand management was difficult, and that it had subtle damaging effects including undermining the advantages of sound finance (balanced budgets) and encouraging inflation. To some extent Keynesianism suffered from its own success in that the post-war period largely avoided periods of devastating unemployment and lost production. However, Keynesianism still shows up in the form of new Keynesian economics, which attempts to merge neoclassical economics with some Keynesian policy conclusions.

At his best Keynes was a wonderful craftsman of the English language and his wonderful fluency of usage is in evidence at times in the General Theory, e.g. Chapter 12 dealing with "The State of Long Term Expectation" is considered by some as an example of the best single chapters about the stock market. However, much of the book shows Keynes at his worst in terms of the English language with long complicated sentence structures uncharacteristic of his style of writing seen in previous books and articles

Similar research was done earlier by economists such as Michał Kalecki, however it was Keynes work which became the most famous.

Although the book made the Modern Library List of Best 20th-Century Nonfiction, more conservative journals have been very critical of the book. It made the Intercollegiate Studies Institute's 50 Worst Books of the Twentieth Century and was at #10 on Human Events' Ten Most Harmful Books of the 19th and 20th Centuries